Rich Man, Poor Man Gluers and sawyers from the
furniture factories in Galax near the mountains of Virginia lost their jobs last
year when American retailers decided they could find a better supplier in China.
At the other end of the furniture industry Robert Nardelli lost his job this
month when Home Depot decided it could find a better chief executive in his
deputy. But any likeness ends there. Mr. Nardelli’s exit was as extravagantly
rewarded as his occupation of the corner office had been. Next to his $ 210
million severance pay, the redundant woodworkers packages were mean to the point
of provocation (激怒). That’s the way it goes all over the rich
world. If you look back 20 years, the total pay of the typical top American
manager has increased from roughly 40 times the average--the level for four
decades -- to 110 times the average now. These are the glory days of global
capitalism. The mix of technology and economic integration transforming the
world has created unparalleled prosperity. In the past five years the world has
seen faster growth than at any time since the early 1970s. Having joined the
global labor force, hundreds of millions of people in developing countries have
won the chance to escape squalor (肮脏) and poverty. Hundreds of millions more
stand to join them. That promises to improve the lot of humanity
as a whole incalculably. But in the rich world labor’s share of GDP has fallen
to historic lows, while profits are soaring. A clamor is abroad that Mr.
Nardelli and his friends among the top hundredth -- or even the top thousandth
-- of the population are seizing the lion’s share of globalization’s gains.
Meanwhile everyone else -- not just blue-collar factory workers but also the
wider office -- working middle class -- shuffles along, grimly waiting for the
next round of cost-cuts. Fear and clothing Signs of a
backlash abound. Stephen Roach, the chief economist at Morgan Stanley, has
counted 27 pieces of anti-China legislation in Congress since early 2005. The
German Marshall Fund found last year that, although most people still say they
favor free trade, more than half of Americans want to protect domestic companies
from foreign competition even if that slows economic growth. In a hint of
labor’s possible resurgence, the House of Representatives has just voted to
raise the federal minimum wage for the first time in a decade. Even Japan is
alarmed about inequality, stagnant (不景气的) wages and jobs going to China. Europe
has tied itself in knots trying to "manage" trade in Chinese
textiles. Should you blame your computer The panic
comes in part from a rush to lump all the blame on globalization. Technology --
an even less resistible force -- is also destroying white- and blue-collar tasks
in a puff of automation and may play a bigger role in explaining rising wage
inequality. The distinctions between technology and globalization count, if only
because people tend to welcome computers but condemn foreigners (whether as
competitors or immigrants). That makes technology easier to defend.
For economists, the debate about whether technology or globalization is
responsible for capital’s rewards outpacing those of labor is crucial,
complicated and unresolved. One school, which blames globalization, argues that
the rocketing profits and sluggish middling wages of the past few years are the
long-lasting results of trade, as all those new developing-country workers enter
the labor market. This school says that technology helps workers by increasing
their productivity and benefits them in other aspects. The opposing school
retorts(反驳) that technology does not increase wages immediately as they blaming
globalization say, and some sorts of information technology seem to boost the
returns to capital instead. The first rule is to avoid harming
the very miracle that generates so much wealth. Take for instance the arguments
about high executive pay. Some say this is simply a matter of governance -- and
forcing company boards to work better. If only it were that simple. High pay is,
by and large, the price needed to attract and motivate gifted managers, as our
special report argues in this issue. The abuses of companies such as Home Depot
obscure how most high pay has been caused not by powerful bosses fixing their
own wages, but by the changing job of the chief executive, the growth of large
companies and the competitive market for talent. Executive-pay restrictions
would not put that horse back in its box, but they would harm
companies. If the winners are difficult to curb without doing
damage to your economy, the losers are tough to help. Doling out aid for the
victims of trade makes sense in theory; but in practice it is increasingly hard
to do. When the jobs going abroad are not whole assembly lines, but bits of
departments, how exactly do you pick out the person who has lost his job to
globalization from the millions of people changing jobs for other reasons And,
hardhearted though it may sound, most of the gains from trade and technology
alike come from the way they redeploy investment and labor to activities that
create more wealth. That, like all change, can be painful; but it is what makes
a country richer. A policy locking people into jobs that could be better done
elsewhere is self-defeating. The limits of redistribution
If protectionism will not help the losers, what about using the tax
system Some argue that redistributing more cash from the Nardellis to the
Galaxians would not just make society less unequal; it would also buy
middle-class support for globalization. In fact the two arguments should be kept
separate. This newspaper has long argued that a mobile society
is better than an equal one: disparities are tolerable if combined with
meritocracy and general economic advance. For decades America has shown how
dynamic economies are better than equality-driven ones at generating overall
prosperity. That still leaves plenty of room to debate how progressive to make
taxation, or how lavish to make public services. But a society would want
compelling evidence that the social contract had been torn up before flexing the
tax system to offset what may turn out to be only temporary fluctuations in
relative incomes. And it makes little sense for free-traders to use taxes to buy
off people from voting for protectionism, when doing so would in any case be
against their interests. Active, not reactive Instead,
the way to ease globalization is the same as the way to ease other sorts of
economic change, including the impact of technology. The aim is to help people
to move jobs as comparative advantage shifts rapidly from one activity to the
next. That means less friction in labor markets and regulatory systems that help
investment. It means an education system that equips people with general skills
that make them mobile. It means detaching health care and pensions from
employment, so that every time you move your job, you are not risking an awful
lot else besides. And for those who lose their jobs -- from whatever cause -- it
means beefing up assistance: generous training and active policies to help them
find work. None of that comes cheap -- and much of it takes
years to work. But an economy that gains from globalization can more easily find
the money to pay for it all. The business people and politicians gathering on
their Swiss Alp next week should certainly spend more time worrying about the
citizens of Galax; but they also need to be far more courageous about defending
a process that can do so much good even if its impact can sometimes appear so
cruel. Compared with Mr. Nardelli’s severance pay, the woodworkers’ ______.
A.seemed to be redundant B.irritated them C.satisfied them D.was close to Mr. Nardelli’s