TEXT D Pundits who want to sound
judicious are fond of warning against generalizing. Each country is different,
they say, and no one story fits all of Asia. This is, of course, silly, all of
these economies plunged into economic crisis within a few months of each other,
so they must have had something in common. In fact, the logic of
catastrophe was pretty much the same in Thailand, Malaysia, Indonesia and South
Korea. (Japan is a very different story. ) In each case investors--mainly, but
not entirely, foreign banks who had made short-term loans--all tried to pull
their money out at the same time. The result was a combined banking and currency
crisis, a banking crisis because no bank can convert all its assets into cash on
short notice, a currency crisis because panicked investors were trying not only
to convert long-term assets into cash, but to convert baht or rupiah into
dollars. In the face of the stampede, governments had no good options. If they
let their currencies plunge, inflation would soar and companies that had
borrowed in dollars would go bankrupt; if they tried to support their currencies
by pushing up interest rates, the same firms would probably go bust from the
combination of debt burden and recession. In practice, countries split the
difference--and paid a heavy price regardless. Was the crisis a
punishment for bad economic management Like most cliches, the catchphrase
"crony capitalism" has prospered because it gets at something real: excessively
cozy relationships between government and business really did lead to a lot of
bad investments. The still primitive financial structure of Asian business also
made the economies peculiarly vulnerable to a loss of confidence. But the
punishment was surely disproportionate to the crime, and many investments that
look foolish in retrospect seemed sensible at the time. Given
that there were no good policy options, was the policy response mainly on the
right track There was frantic blame-shifting when everything in Asia seemed to
be going wrong; now there is a race to claim credit when some things have
started to go right. The International Monetary Fund points to Korea’s
recovery--and more generally to the fact that the sky didn’t fall after all--as
proof that its policy recommendations were right. Never mind that other IMF
clients have done far worse, and that the economy of Malaysia---which refused
IMF help, and horrified respectable opinion by imposing capital controls---also
seems to be on the mend. Malaysia’s Prime Minister, by contrast, claims full
credit for any good news--even though neighbouring economies also seem to have
bottomed out. The truth is that an observer without any ax to
grind would probably conclude that none of the policies adopted either on or in
defiance of the IMF’s advice made much difference either way. Budget policies,
interest rate policies, banking reform--whatever countries tried, just about all
the capital that could flee, did. And when there was no more money to run, the
natural recuperative powers of the economies finally began to prevail. At best,
the money doctors who purported to offer cures provided a helpful bedside
manner; at worst, they were like medieval physicians who prescribed bleeding as
a remedy for all ills. Will the patients stage a full recovery
It depends on exactly what you mean by "full". South Korea’s industrial
production is already above its pre-crisis level; but in the spring of 1997
anyone who had predicted zero growth in Korean industry over the next two years
would have been regarded as a reckless doomsayer. So if by recovery you mean not
just a return to growth, but one that brings the region’s performance back to
something like what people used to regard as the Asian norm, they have a long
way to go. According to the passage, which of the following is NOT the writer’s opinion
A.Countries paid a heavy price for whichever measure taken. B.Countries all found themselves in an economic dilemma. C.Withdrawal of foreign capital resulted in the crisis. D.Most governments chose one of the two options.